Problem of plenty

Published : Jan 12, 2007 00:00 IST

U.S. FEDERAL RESERVE Chairman Ben Bernanke at the Strategic Economic Dialogue in Beijing's Great Hall of the People on December 14. - AP

U.S. FEDERAL RESERVE Chairman Ben Bernanke at the Strategic Economic Dialogue in Beijing's Great Hall of the People on December 14. - AP

While the U.S.' role in global growth and crisis is well known, China is now emerging as the cause of capitalism's crisis of overproduction.

"THE world [is] investing too little," according to one prominent economist. "The current situation has its roots in a series of crises over the last decade that were caused by excessive investment, such as the Japanese asset bubble, the crises in emerging Asia and Latin America, and most recently, the IT [information technology] bubble. Investment has fallen off sharply since, with only very cautious recovery."

Overcapacity has been the key link between the global economy in the Clinton era and the Bush period. The crisis has been particularly severe in the so-called core industries. At the beginning of the 21st century, the American computer industry's computer capacity was rising at 40 per cent annually, far above projected increases in demand. The world auto industry was selling just 74 per cent of the 70.1 million cars it made each year, creating a profitability crunch for the weakest players, such as the former giant General Motors, which lost $10.6 billion in 2005, and Ford, which lost $7.24 billion in the first nine months of 2006. In steel, global excess capacity neared 20 per cent. It was estimated, in volume terms, to be an astounding 200 million tonnes, so that plans by steel-producing countries to reduce capacity by 100 million tonnes by 2005 would still leave "a sizable amount of capacity which... would not be viable". In telecommunications, according to Robert Brenner, overcapitalisation has resulted in a "mountainous glut: the utilisation rate of telecom networks hovers today at a disastrously low 2.5-3 per cent, that of undersea cable at just 13 per cent". As former General Electric chairman Jack Welch put it, there has been "excess capacity in almost every industry".

Global overcapacity has made further investment simply unprofitable, which significantly dampens global economic growth. In Europe, for instance, gross domestic product (GDP) growth has averaged only 1.45 per cent in the last few years. And if countries are not investing in their economic futures, then growth will continue to stagnate and possibly lead to a global recession.

China and the United States, however, appear to be bucking the trend, though GDP growth in the U.S. has flattened recently. But rather than signs of health, growth in these two economies - and their ever more symbiotic relationship with each other - may actually be an indicator of crisis. The centrality of the U.S. to both global growth and global crisis is well known. What is new is China's critical role. Once regarded as the greatest achievement of this era of globalisation, China's integration into the global economy is, according to an excellent analysis by political economist Ho-fung Hung (in the paper "The Rise of China and the Global Overaccummulation Crisis", presented at the Global Division of the Annual Meeting of the Society for the Study of Social Problems, August 10-12, 2006, Montreal, Canada), emerging as a central cause of global capitalism's crisis of overproduction.

China's 8-10 per cent annual growth rate has probably been the principal stimulus of growth in the world economy in the last decade. Chinese imports, for instance, helped to end Japan's decade-long stagnation in 2003. In order to satisfy China's thirst for capital and technology-intensive goods, Japanese exports shot up by a record 44 per cent, or $60 billion. Indeed, China became the main destination for Asia's exports, accounting for 31 per cent, while Japan's share dropped from 20 to 10 per cent. Singapore's The Straits Times pointed out, "In country-by-country profiles, China is now the overwhelming driver of export growth in Taiwan and the Philippines, and the majority buyer of products from Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, and Australia."

At the same time, China has become a central contributor to the crisis of global overcapacity. Even as investment declined sharply in many economies in response to the surfeit of productive capacity, particularly in Japan and other East Asian economies, it increased at a break-neck pace in China. Investment in China was not just the obverse of disinvestment elsewhere, although the shutting down of facilities and sloughing off of labour was significant not only in Japan and the U.S. but in countries on China's periphery, such as the Philippines, Thailand and Malaysia. China was significantly beefing up its industrial capacity and not simply absorbing capacity eliminated elsewhere. At the same time, the ability of the Chinese market to absorb its own industrial output was limited.

A major actor in overinvestment was transnational capital. In the late 1980s and the 1990s, transnational corporations (TNCs) saw China as the last frontier, the unlimited market that could endlessly absorb investment and endlessly throw off profitable returns. However, China's restrictive rules on trade and investment forced TNCs to locate most of their production processes in the country instead of outsourcing only a select number of them. Analysts termed such TNC production activities "excessive internalisation". By playing according to China's rules, TNCs ended up overinvesting in the country and building up a manufacturing base that produced more than China or even the rest of the world could consume.

By the turn of the millennium, the dream of exploiting a limitless market had vanished. Foreign companies headed for China not so much to sell to millions of newly prosperous Chinese customers but rather to make China a manufacturing base for global markets and take advantage of its inexhaustible supply of cheap labour. Typical of companies that found themselves in this quandary was Philips, the Dutch electronics manufacturer. Philips operates 23 factories in China and produces about $5 billion worth of goods, but two-thirds of its production is exported.

The other set of actors promoting overcapacity were local governments, which invested in and built up key industries. While these efforts are often "well-planned and executed at the local level", notes Ho-fung Hung, "the totality of these efforts combined... entail anarchic competition among localities, resulting in uncoordinated construction of redundant production capacity and infrastructure".

As a result, idle capacity in such key sectors as steel, automobile, cement, aluminium and real estate has been soaring since the mid-1990s, with estimates that over 75 per cent of China's industries are currently plagued by overcapacity and that fixed asset investments in industries already experiencing overinvestment account for 40-50 per cent of China's GDP growth in 2005. China's State Development and Reform Commission projects that the automobile industry will produce double what the market can absorb by 2010. The impact on profitability is not to be underestimated if we are to believe government statistics: at the end of 2005, Hung points out, the average annual profit growth rate of all major enterprises had plunged by half and the total deficit of losing enterprises had increased sharply by 57.6 per cent.

The Chinese government can mitigate excess capacity by expanding people's purchasing power via a policy of income and asset redistribution. Doing so would probably mean slower growth but more domestic and global stability. This is what China's so-called "New Left" intellectuals and policy analysts have been advising. China's authorities, however, have apparently chosen to continue the old strategy of dominating world markets by exploiting the country's cheap labour. Although China's population is 1.3 billion, 700 million people - or over half - live in the countryside and earn an average of just $285 a year, according to some estimates. This reserve army of rural poor has enabled manufacturers, both foreign and local, to keep wages down.

Aside from the potentially destabilising political effects of regressive income distribution, the low-wage strategy, as Hung points out, "impedes the growth of consumption relative to the phenomenal economic expansion and great leap of investment". In other words, the global crisis of overproduction will worsen as China continues to dump its industrial production on global markets constrained by slow growth.

Chinese production and American consumption are like the proverbial prisoners who seek to break free from one another but cannot because they are chained together. This relationship is increasingly taking the form of a vicious cycle. On the one hand, China's break-neck growth has increasingly depended on the ability of American consumers to continue their consumption of much of the output of China's production brought about by excessive investment. On the other hand, the U.S.' high consumption rate depends on Beijing lending the U.S.' private and public sectors a significant portion of the trillion-plus dollars it has accumulated from its yawning trade surplus with Washington.

This chain-gang relationship, says Rajan, is "unsustainable". Both the U.S. and the IMF have decried what they call "global macroeconomic imbalances" and called on China to revalue the renminbi (people's currency) to reduce its trade surplus with the U.S. Yet China cannot really abandon its cheap currency policy.

Along with cheap labour, cheap currency is part of China's successful formula of export-oriented production. And the U.S. really cannot afford to be too tough on China since it depends on that open line of credit to Beijing to continue feeding the middle-class spending that sustains its own economic growth.

This is the reason the mid-December visit to Beijing of a high-powered U.S. team led by Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke and Treasury Secretary Hank Paulson to pressure China on its currency and its trade surplus with the U.S. unfolded like a classic Chinese opera where the audience knew in advance how each of the characters would behave.

"Global macroeconomic imbalances" is the IMF's euphemistic description of the state of the world economy. But what is unfolding is really a crisis of overproduction.

Thanks to Chinese factories and American consumers, the crisis is likely to get worse.

Walden Bello is Professor of Sociology at the University of the Philippines and executive director of the Bangkok-based research and advocacy institute Focus on the Global South.

Sign in to Unlock member-only benefits!
  • Bookmark stories to read later.
  • Comment on stories to start conversations.
  • Subscribe to our newsletters.
  • Get notified about discounts and offers to our products.
Sign in

Comments

Comments have to be in English, and in full sentences. They cannot be abusive or personal. Please abide to our community guidelines for posting your comment