Why inflation still matters

Published : Dec 15, 2006 00:00 IST

The recent rise in inflation reflects not higher growth but economic mismanagement.

PERHAPS more than any other purely economic issue, inflation has always been a pressing socio-political concern in India. This is because a vast majority of our working people receive incomes that are not indexed to prices, and are therefore directly and adversely affected especially by the rise in prices of necessities. Since money wages and the incomes of small businesses of the self-employed adjust to rising prices only with a lag, their real incomes get eroded over time. So inflation has direct consequences for income distribution.

Of course, periods of slow price rise are not always beneficial, even for the poor. If low inflation is the result of restrictive macroeconomic policies that reduce economic activity and employment growth, its impact can be even worse for the mass of people than the impact of moderate inflation rates, which are associated with rising aggregate income and employment.

Recent macroeconomic policy discussions have been rather complacent about the issue of inflation, especially given the relatively low rates that prevailed over much of the past decade. However, in the past year the increase in the overall inflation rate as well as the rise in prices of particular commodities have brought into question both the sustainability of the current economic growth process and the efficacy of public management of price rise in particular sectors.

Consumer prices have definitely increased in the recent past such that the annual rate of inflation at present is between 6 and 7 per cent. Movements in the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) show that the recent rise has been sharpest in the case of food articles, including food grains, which still form the most basic of necessary goods. Indeed, for some commodity groups such as pulses, prices rose by nearly 33 per cent between January and November (chart on page 96).

What has brought about this recent acceleration of inflation in the economy? In a statement before Parliament in July (as reported in the Rajya Sabha proceedings of July 24, 2006), Finance Minister P. Chidambaram claimed that this was the result of three forces. According to him, two of these are completely out of the government's control.

The first factor, according to Chidambaram, was the cost-push effect emanating from the hardening of world commodity prices, such as oil and other fuels, minerals and metals. With world prices in these increasing, it is only to be expected that domestic prices will also rise. However, the fact is that global oil prices have been falling in recent times and are now below the levels they stood at even one and a half years ago. The same is true of most agricultural commodities and of some imported minerals and metals. So cost-push inflation because of higher import prices is unlikely to explain the rise in prices after June 2006.

The second factor he mentioned was the demand-pull effect of higher economic growth, which puts pressure on available supplies and therefore leads to what he described as a temporary rise in prices. Certainly, there is evidence that rapid growth in some sectors has put pressure on raw material supplies and may lead to bottlenecks in the supply of particular inputs, including not only raw materials and intermediates but also some forms of skilled labour.

However, this process - and the resulting price rise - is not a necessary concomitant of high growth. It is worth noting that the Chinese economy has grown very rapidly for nearly 30 years, with only moderate inflation. Even in the current year, when the Chinese economy is apparently growing by more than 10 per cent in real terms, inflation has been only 1.4 per cent at an annual rate. So, clearly, rapid growth in domestic demand need not lead to higher inflation.

Further, since China is also a more import-dependent economy than India, importing a greater proportion of inputs for the manufacturing sector, it should have been more adversely affected by the rise in world commodity prices that Chidambaram spoke of than India. Instead, inflation rates have been lower than in the past!

The third factor that Chidambaram referred to was "supply shocks", which would be better described as poor management of critical areas of the economy. Here, in fact, the Finance Minister probably hit the nail on the head, perhaps inadvertently. He referred to the mismatch between demand and supply in important commodities such as wheat, pulses and sugar, suggesting that unexpected output shortfalls of these crops led to a temporary rise in prices, and that this increase would get mitigated once supplies were enhanced, for instance, through imports.

But this is only part of the story. It is misleading to speak only of crop failures for what happened was essentially a policy-created process that was subsequently mismanaged. The government allowed the entry of large (and multinational) private players into the grain trade and opened up the futures market for trading in these essential commodities, which all have a history of being hoarded. Having thus allowed for speculation, the government was then very surprised when it actually happened.

In the case of wheat, for example, the Food Corporation of India was unable to procure adequate amounts for the public distribution system (PDS) because private players such as Cargill were offering farmers higher prices. Procurement declined by nearly 40 per cent compared with last year, and wheat stocks fell by 20 per cent to less than 7 million tonnes. This was not only inadequate for the requirements of the government in terms of the PDS and school meals programmes but also insufficient to quell speculative activity in wheat markets when prices started to rise.

Eventually, the government was forced to import wheat at prices several times higher than what it had been willing to pay farmers, and in the meantime consumers had to cope with rising prices of wheat. A similar story operates for pulses except that mitigating imports have not yet occurred, so the price rise continues unabated.

This is such expensive incompetence that in any country with real democratic accountability, heads would have rolled. But in India, Ministers can talk glibly of "supply-demand imbalances" as if these were completely outside the purview of government.

The government is indeed now concerned about inflation, but unfortunately, the knee-jerk response has been to use the blunt instrument of the interest rate. In the past months, the Reserve Bank of India's discount rate has been increased three times, most recently on October 31. But this affects all productive sectors alike and has disproportionately negative effects upon small enterprises that already find it more difficult to get bank credit.

Instead of this blanket measure, there should have been more nuanced and directed interventions addressing the sectors in which speculative bubbles are clearly visible. The stock market, for instance, continues to be irrationally exuberant, and the imposition of a capital gains tax at this point could only have a salutary effect, besides raising more revenue for the government. The real estate market is clearly overheating - house prices in the metros are estimated to have more than doubled in the past two years. Yet the banking system and the income tax structure continue to encourage property loans.

Clearly, the recent rise in inflation reflects not higher growth but economic mismanagement.

Sign in to Unlock member-only benefits!
  • Bookmark stories to read later.
  • Comment on stories to start conversations.
  • Subscribe to our newsletters.
  • Get notified about discounts and offers to our products.
Sign in

Comments

Comments have to be in English, and in full sentences. They cannot be abusive or personal. Please abide to our community guidelines for posting your comment