The price burden

Published : Apr 10, 2009 00:00 IST

ARKO DUTTA/RUETERS

ARKO DUTTA/RUETERS

PRICE movements are fundamentally about income distribution. When prices of certain commodities go up faster than those of others, it implies reduced real incomes for those who sell the latter. The most obvious direct effect is of course on real wages because when the price of labour, or money wages, does not keep pace with the items that form the consumption basket of workers, it implies reduced real wages of workers.

But other categories of workers are also affected: when agricultural crop prices do not go up as much as the input costs of cultivation or of other goods that farmers have to buy, it affects the real incomes of farmers. Similar is the case of non-agricultural petty producers, who can also be considered as self-employed workers.

That is why prices are also political, or rather, why inflation can be such a hot political issue especially before elections. The general perception is that high inflation is unpopular, for the obvious reason that it cuts into the real income of most people. Therefore, in the middle of last year when the increase in prices had become an issue of widespread concern, it essentially reflected the concern that the issue was impacting on the real incomes of most ordinary people.

The recent decline in inflation rates has led many to believe that this is no longer a concern. But, in terms of political impact, what needs to be examined is the extent to which inflation of the past few years has affected real incomes. In other words, do people feel better off or worse off than they did five years ago when the UPA government came to power?

It is important in this regard to be aware of the difference between inflation and price levels. Inflation refers to the change in prices, and any positive rate of inflation, however low, indicates that prices are rising. So even if the inflation rate is coming down, it does not mean prices are coming down, it only means that prices are increasing at a slower rate than before. This is a mistake commonly made by media commentators, who confuse a decline in inflation rates with a decline in prices. If prices themselves actually come down, then that is deflation.

Why does this matter? Because even if the inflation rate slows down or comes down to zero, it simply means that the price level stays at the level it had reached, which may be felt to be a very high level by those whose nominal incomes have not increased. So if prices had risen very dramatically last year, but have now slowed down, this may still be experienced as very high price levels by those whose wages and salaries have not increased much over the whole period.

The accompanying chart shows how consumer prices the price of the basket of goods estimated to be consumed by different groups of workers - have moved since April 2004, just before the last general election. Some points of note emerge from this chart. First, overall inflation has been quite high for both sets of workers over this period, with consumer prices increasing by around 40 per cent over this five-year period. It is extremely unlikely that nominal wage incomes for most workers in urban or rural areas have increased by that much in this period, although we will have to wait for large sample survey data to check on this.

Certainly, the large sample survey data of the past suggested little change in nominal wage and self-employed incomes between 1999-2000 and 2004-05, especially in the informal sector. It is likely that this trend has continued into the past five years as well. Micro case studies suggest that nominal remuneration for a significant proportion of self-employed workers such as home-based workers has even declined in recent times, suggesting that real incomes have plummeted quite dramatically.

Second, while the consumer price index for industrial workers was increasing more rapidly until October 2006, the index for agricultural labourers too has been moving up more rapidly thereafter. The main reason is probably the faster increase in the price of food, since the food index even for industrial workers has moved up more rapidly since October 2006.

But higher inflation need not always be the greater problem in fact, sometimes the opposite can be true. This is not always and inevitably the case it depends on what is happening to nominal incomes as well. So even falling inflation can be of concern, if the nominal incomes of enough people fall even faster. And deflation, if it is associated with declining economic activity and employment, can be really bad news.

That is why the news, on March 19, that the wholesale price index (WPI) for all commodities had barely increased on an annual basis, going up at the historically low rate of 0.44 per cent, gave rise to mixed reactions. Some welcomed it, on the grounds that it reflected an easing of the inflationary pressures that seemed so marked just a few months ago. Others (notably the Chairman of the Prime Ministers Economic Advisory Council) dismissed the lower inflation rate as nothing but a base effect of the earlier high prices, as the economy stabilises at those price levels. Others were actually alarmed at this possible sign that the economy is entering a deflationary phase, in which output and employment may even shrink.

Yet hardly any commentators dwelt on the income distribution aspect of the inflation, which is arguably the most significant consequence, at least politically. To understand the distributive implications, the overall inflation rate has to be unpackaged into its component parts, to understand which sectors and which categories of producers and consumers are affected in different ways.

An examination of the disaggregated changes in the latest WPI numbers throws up some surprising, even alarming, results. The accompanying table provides information on year-on-year percentage changes (or annual inflation rates) for different categories of goods.

While overall inflation has indeed slowed down to almost no change in the aggregate price level, food prices have continued to increase. Foodgrain prices have gone up the most by more than 10 per cent and this cannot be blamed on higher procurement prices alone, since the prices of pulses, which are not covered by public procurement, have also gone up just as much.

The prices of fruits and vegetables and eggs, fish and meat have also increased, even if not by as much as for foodgrains. The only food category for which prices have fallen is edible oils, which reflects the decline in oilseed prices as world prices have crashed. Other food articles prices have increased by more than one-fifth in this one year.

So all householders who wonder how inflation could be falling when they keep facing higher prices when they go to the market are right in one important respect food prices are indeed still rising, despite the stability of the overall price level. And this will obviously affect household budgets, especially among the poor for whom food still accounts for more than half of total household expenditure. It is worth remembering that food prices have always been politically sensitive: there are elections that are supposed to have been won or lost over the price of onions.

Another major item of essential consumption has also increased in price: that of drugs and medicines has gone up by 4.5 per cent, which obviously impacts upon the entire population, but especially the bottom half of the population which may find it extremely difficult, if not impossible, to meet such expenditures in times of stringency.

But these are not the only disturbing thing about the disaggregated data. A remarkable feature is how non-food primary product prices have moved. The prices of fibres mainly cotton, jute and silk have barely increased at all.

Oilseed prices have fallen by more than 5 per cent. This immediately affects all the producers of cash crops, who will be getting the same or less for their products even as they pay significantly more for food. They are also paying more for fertilizer and pesticides, whose prices have increased by more than 5 per cent.

Meanwhile, several manufactured goods have also declined in price over the past year. Some of the sharpest price declines have occurred in iron and steel (a decline of nearly 17 per cent) and non-ferrous metals (a decline of nearly 11 per cent). This has happened mostly in the very recent period, as the impact of the global recession fed into trade prices. Indeed, the sheer rapidity and extent of the price changes for traded goods is remarkable.

For example, the price of fibres rose by 12.1 per cent between March 8, 2008, and January 10, 2009, and then plummeted by 9.3 per cent in just the past two months. While some of this can be explained by seasonality (such as the cotton harvest that comes around December-January) the decline this year is much sharper than in previous years and reflects international prices as well. Overall, the price index of manufactured goods increased slightly by 2 per cent until January 10, and subsequently fell by 0.65 per cent to March 7, 2009.

What does all this add up to? What it suggests a worrying combination of falling prices faced by agriculturalists who produce cash crops as well as petty producers and others who produce manufactured goods, even as the prices of essential items like food and medicines continue to rise. These groups and their families alone account for the majority of the population in the country. The latest figures ought to worry the government that is still in power, for this combination could amount to electoral dynamite.

Sign in to Unlock member-only benefits!
  • Bookmark stories to read later.
  • Comment on stories to start conversations.
  • Subscribe to our newsletters.
  • Get notified about discounts and offers to our products.
Sign in

Comments

Comments have to be in English, and in full sentences. They cannot be abusive or personal. Please abide to our community guidelines for posting your comment