Opening the sluice gates

Published : Feb 27, 2004 00:00 IST

A reading of the extensive literature on the "feast-or-famine" syndrome characteristic of capital flows to emerging markets shows that the government, by beginning the journey to full convertibility of the rupee, has opened the sluice gates to outflows that can empty its foreign exchange reserve.

ON February 4, the Reserve Bank of India took a major step forward towards full convertibility of the rupee. It announced that resident Indians can, with immediate effect, remit up to $25,000 a calendar year for any current or capital account transaction, or a combination of both. This implies that resident Indians would not just be able to open and operate foreign currency accounts outside India, but can use the money remitted to those accounts to acquire financial or immovable assets without prior approval from RBI.

On the surface, the sum of $25,000 may appear small, especially when compared to net capital inflows into the country of $12 billion in 2002-03 and $6 billion in the first quarter (April-June) of 2003-04, and reserve accumulation of $17 billion during 2002-03, and around $25 billion during April-December 2003. But looked at otherwise, if one million Indians, or just one per cent of the country's population, choose to avail themsleves of the facility in full, the outflow would be adequate to wipe out the foreign exchange reserves accumulated during the first three quarter of a year (2003-04) that has seen record inflows of capital.

It is not India's new and old rich alone who would seek to exploit the new `facility'. The large number of middle class households who have members moving abroad on H1 B visas or for educational purposes would see some reason for holding an account, if not making some investment, abroad. A million may not be a large figure for the number willing every year to transfer the equivalent of Rs.11.5 lakhs abroad at current exchange rates.

Not surprisingly, within a day after the new facility was announced, banks have rushed to the press to advertise their willingness to manage remittances under this head for interested clients.

Needless to say, if all or a large part of capital inflows are consumed in this fashion, it could send out a signal that the country is losing its ability to meet its repatriation commitments, either in the form of the returns that would accrue to foreign investors or in the form of permission to exit from investments in the country. This could slow capital inflows or even result in outflows, leading to a collapse in reserves and a financial crisis. This is typically the way in which countries that are temporarily the favourites of foreign investors and experience a capital inflow surge often find themselves - the victims of outflows that lead to crisis. The "feast-or-famine" syndrome characteristic of capital flows to emerging markets has been documented widely. A reading of that literature does warrant the conclusion that by beginning the journey to full convertibility, the government has opened the sluice gates to outflows that can empty its foreign exchange reserve.

An analysis by RBI of the sources of reserve accumulation over a long period points to the important role of inflows in the form NRI deposits and foreign institutional investor (FII) investments. Outstanding NRI deposits increased from $13.7 billion at end-March 1991 to $31.3 billion at end-September 2003. Cumulative net FII investments increased from $827 million at end-December 1993 to $19.2 billion at end-September 2003. These kinds of investments rarely, if ever at all, finance new investments in the domestic economy. These are also typically inflows that would be reversed in case of any sign of uncertainty.

Thus, comparisons of likely outflows with the size of inflows and the extent of reserve accumulation are not without some basis. Reserve accumulation occurs when RBI is forced to intervene in the foreign currency market and purchase dollars or other foreign currencies. This it is forced to do when large capital inflows result in a surplus of foreign exchange in the system, since the supply of foreign exchange exceeds demands from firms and individuals for permitted current and capital account transactions such as imports, private or business travel, remittance for gifts, donations, study abroad, medical treatment, investment abroad, and so on. When the supply of foreign exchange exceeds such demand, the rupee tends to appreciate vis-a-vis foreign currencies under India's liberalised and market-driven exchange rate regime. A rising rupee increases the dollar value of India's exportables and adversely affects its export competitiveness. It is to prevent such appreciation that RBI has been purchasing foreign exchange in the market and enhancing its reserves.

Beyond a point, however, increasing reserves are a problem for the central bank. When the foreign exchange assets of RBI rise, so do its liabilities, which typically imply an increase in money supply. Since allowing that to happen amounts to losing control of its monetary policy lever, the central bank chooses to retrench other assets such as government securities to sterilise inflows.

Unfortunately for RBI, foreign capital inflows have in recent months been massive and unrelenting. The consequent huge and rapid increase in its reserves, can no more be sterilised easily, since the central bank has already brought down its holding of government securities substantially.

Excessive reserve accumulation is a problem also because of its negative balance of payments implications. Investors bringing in the capital earn minimum returns of around 7 per cent. The maximum would be many multiples of that, especially from capital gains associated with recent investments in the stock market. These returns have to be paid out in foreign exchange. On the other hand, when the dollars flowing into the country are acquired by RBI and invested through central and commercial banks, the returns are much lower. According to RBI, during 2002-03 (July-June), the return on foreign currency assets, excluding capital gains less depreciation, decreased to 2.8 per cent from 4.1 per cent during 2001-02, because of lower international interest rates. This implies that the interest associated with capital inflow and its accretion as reserves involves little foreign exchange earning but substantial foreign exchange payouts.

Finally, from a diplomatic point of view it is becoming increasingly difficult to accumulate reserves in order to prevent currency appreciation. India has been identified along with China as a country whose large reserves prove that it has an "undervalued" currency that discriminates against imports from the U.S. The pressure to allow the currency to appreciate is therefore on the increase.

For all these reasons it had become clear to the central bank and the government that something had to be done to prevent further rapid accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. The choice, therefore, was either to curb flows or to stimulate the demand for foreign exchange. Given its unthinking commitment to liberalisation and "reform", it is the latter route that the government has chosen.

Recent months have, therefore, seen not just irrational and sometime bizarre trade liberalisation manoeuvres, such as across-the-board duty reductions and the licence to bring in laptops duty free as part of baggage, but the relaxation of ceilings on remittances abroad for purposes as varied as education, health and investment. All of these have proved inadequate given the fact that India has proved to be the flavour of the season for foreign investors, who have rushed into the country in herd-like fashion.

IT is this set of circumstances, rather than reasonable decision-making, that has forced the government to all on a sudden liberalise controls on capital account outflows. The sequence has to be noted. First, regulations regarding purely financial inflows are liberalised to attract capital into the country so as finance the outflows that trade liberalization was expected to result in. Since the initial response of foreign investors was lukewarm, further liberalisation, in the form of relaxing ceilings on FII holdings of equity in firms in different sectors, was resorted to.

Suddenly, for reasons extraneous to the performance of the India economy, which has grown at an indifferent rate for at least three consecutive years before the current "recovery", inflows accelerate. Unable to manage those inflows, the government attempts to encourage foreign exchange profligacy through liberalisation of foreign exchange access for various current account transactions. When even that proves inadequate, it opts for capital account convertibility.

The problem is that when controls on capital account outflows are liberalised, it is difficult to control the volume of outflows. And if large outflows raise the threat of depreciation in the value of the rupee, outflows accelerate and capital flight out of rupee-denominated assets would occur.

Having whetted the appetite of India's rich for a financial foothold abroad, it would be extremely difficult to reverse the decision. Moreover, any such reversal would encourage the flight of financial investors out of the country. A currency and financial collapse would be inevitable. In short, the sluice gates have been opened. It is, therefore, clearly time to prepare for the coming crisis.

Sign in to Unlock member-only benefits!
  • Bookmark stories to read later.
  • Comment on stories to start conversations.
  • Subscribe to our newsletters.
  • Get notified about discounts and offers to our products.
Sign in

Comments

Comments have to be in English, and in full sentences. They cannot be abusive or personal. Please abide to our community guidelines for posting your comment