Repression of labour

Published : Jan 02, 2004 00:00 IST

The anti-labour stance of the Indian state is driven by a liberal market-oriented economic paradigm that has proved to be a disaster in Latin America.

FOR some time now, it has been evident that the stance of the Central government - in terms of the executive authority and policymakers - is anti-labour. It is now apparent that the same tendency is also increasingly prevalent among the judiciary, which has delivered a series of judgments that effectively operate to reduce the bargaining power and rights of workers. The recent Supreme Court judgment on the right of public employees to go on strike, the decision of a Kolkata High Court Judge to ban rallies on weekdays (which then was reversed); the Supreme Court's reversal of its own previous judgment regarding the right to regular employment of contract workers employed for prolonged periods - all these are indications of a much broader and more dangerous socio-economic process.

There is an underlying economic paradigm in all this, which essentially is the neo-liberal market-oriented framework. This argues that labour market "flexibility" is crucial for increasing investment and therefore employment and also for ensuring external competitiveness in a difficult international environment. In this perception, legal protection afforded to workers, in the form of curbs on employers' ability to hire and fire workers at will, minimum wages or granting freedom to engage in collective action such as the right to strike, all actually operate to reduce employment.

In addition, in India there is another argument that is frequently accepted even by well-meaning people with a concern for the poor - that the dualism in the labour market in India means that there is a conflict between organised workers and those in the unorganised sector. It is often argued that the recognised trade unions ignore the problems of the workers in the informal sector; that protection given to organised workers actually allows or even militates against the improvement of conditions of unorganised workers who are anyway much worse off. This perception then leads even some progressive people to accept that the "privileges" extended to organised sector workers can be withdrawn since they are anyway so much better off than most other workers in the economy.

This argument is based on poor politics and even worse economics. The politics is wrong because in fact any struggle over workers' rights necessarily affects all workers, even if this is not immediately evident to particular categories of workers. It is amply clear even from the Indian experience that every attack on organised workers has also reduced the bargaining power of unorganised workers, that periods of repression of organised labour have also been periods when informal sector workers find themselves even more exploited.

The neo-liberal economic argument is that the rules that restrict hiring and firing put undue pressure on larger employers and prevent smaller firms from expanding even when the economics of their situation otherwise warrants it. This creates a dualistic set-up in which the organised or formal sector necessarily remains limited in terms of aggregate employment and most workers, who remain in the unorganised sector, are, therefore, denied the benefits of any protection at all.

The resulting dualism is characterised by an organised (or larger scale) sector, which has relatively low employment, and an unorganised (or smaller scale) sector, which has low investment. If aggregate economic activity is to break out of this dualism and marry the advantages of both sectors, the argument goes, it is necessary to get rid of the constraints put on large employers in the matter of labour relations. The purpose of various recent interventions - the recommendations of the Second National Labour Commission, the recent court judgment, the attempts to create more "flexible" and less protective labour legislation - is supposedly to get rid of these constraints on employers.

The belief is obviously that reducing such "rigidities" and curbing the power of organised labour will increase private investment, increase economic activity and improve productivity. All these, in turn, will improve external competitiveness, which is considered to be so important these days.

The chief problem with this argument is that it completely ignores the major forces affecting investment, economic activity and therefore employment. It is now accepted across the world that aggregate investment does not respond to changes in the wage rate but to broader macroeconomic conditions such as the level of demand, the amount of public investment, the expectation of external markets, and so on. Labour costs are never viewed in isolation but only in relation to labour productivity which, in turn, is affected not only by the level of well-being, skill and education of the workers themselves but also by infrastructure conditions, the technology used in production, and so on. In such a context, greater "flexibility" in labour markets might simply mean the perpetuation of low wage-low productivity practices by employers, rather than more economic growth.

While there is a formidable array of rights accepted by the Constitution for workers, and protective legislation as well, the problem is that they are rarely achieved or enforced. Typically, they can only be even minimally enforced in the organised sector. It is currently being argued by neo-liberal economists and others that these laws, which restrict employers' rights to dismiss workers at will and stipulate some degree of permanency of employment, act as a major drag on the profitability of the organised sector and on its ability to compete with more flexible labour relations elsewhere. In this perception, a shift towards a more universal contract-based system of labour relations, with no assumptions of permanency of employment, is required to ensure economic progress based on private enterprise within the current context.

But, it can be argued in response to this that labour laws are far less significant as factors in affecting private investment and, therefore, employment than more standard macroeconomic variables and profitability indicators. Thus, the condition and cost of physical infrastructure, the efficiency of workers as determined by social infrastructure, and the policies that determine access to credit for fixed and working capital as well as other forms of access to capital, all play important roles in determining overall investment and its allocation across sectors. Expectations of demand and the extent of the market determine the volume of investment.

In the 1990s, advocates of labour repression started arguing that, while all this might be true for closed economies, things are different in open economies. Once international competition becomes important, it is impossible to ignore the need for labour flexibility, so globalisation means that the "old" more protective laws and structures for workers have to be dismantled.

But, the experience of the Latin American economies over the past two decades serves to destroy that argument. Most countries in Latin America went in for drastic liberalisation of their economies after the debt crisis of the early 1980s.

They also went in for policies and laws that dramatically reduced the power of organised labour. The typical package of reduction of public investment, privatisation of state assets, reduced public services, and much lower bargaining power of workers, lead to low wage demands.

The result has been very different from the neo-liberal dream. In the past two decades, investment rates across most of Latin America have gone down. There has been de-industrialisation with a decline in both output shares and absolute levels of employment in manufacturing. The production structure has shifted away from sectors with potential for productivity growth back to the processing of raw materials and primary products. Labour productivity has stagnated. External competitiveness in this region has been based on low wages rather than increasing productivity and so the region's share of world exports has actually fallen.

This should serve as a cautionary example to our own policymakers, and even other bodies such as the judiciary, who appear to be intent on following this unfortunate example. Labour repression cannot be a route to sustained development, especially in countries like India. It can only contribute to the perpetuation of low productivity and insecure employment across the economy.

Sign in to Unlock member-only benefits!
  • Bookmark stories to read later.
  • Comment on stories to start conversations.
  • Subscribe to our newsletters.
  • Get notified about discounts and offers to our products.
Sign in

Comments

Comments have to be in English, and in full sentences. They cannot be abusive or personal. Please abide to our community guidelines for posting your comment