Currency baiting

Published : Nov 05, 2010 00:00 IST

WORLD LEADERS AND country representatives at the International Monetary Fund headquarters during the annual meeting of the IMF and the World Bank in Washington, DC, on October 9.-PTI

WORLD LEADERS AND country representatives at the International Monetary Fund headquarters during the annual meeting of the IMF and the World Bank in Washington, DC, on October 9.-PTI

The U.S.' injection of cheap money at home and its moves to get emerging markets to increase the value of their currencies are a sure recipe for conflict.

THE slanging match over currency and monetary policies at the annual meetings of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank, held over the second weekend of October, points to the fact that global economic governance is in disarray. While the United States sought to mobilise IMF support for an effort to realign exchange rates and ensure an appreciation of the renminbi in the wake of China's reserve accumulation, the Chinese accused the U.S. of destabilising emerging economies by allowing an ultra-loose monetary policy to flood the emerging world with money. The result was that there was little agreement on what needs to be done to drag the world out of stagnation.

Evidence mounts, on the one hand, that the much-touted recovery from the Great Recession of 2008 is yet to gather steam and that unemployment in the developed world remains at intolerable levels. On the other hand, there is still no consensus on how to deal with the problem. Governments in the developed countries are clearly overcome by stimulus fatigue. Having used up a substantial part of the head room they had for deficit spending to bail out the financial sector, and having accumulated much debt in the process, there is scepticism about continuing with a fiscal stimulus. So, increasingly, the push for recovery is moving in two directions.

One is the resort to quantitative easing, or the injection of liquidity into the system through lending by central banks, especially the U.S. Federal Reserve, at near zero interest rates. The other is to increase pressure on emerging market economies, especially China, to allow their exchange rates to appreciate in the hope that it will expand U.S. exports to and reduce its imports from those markets and facilitate a recovery.

The simultaneous advocacy of these two options is a sure recipe for conflict. It is widely accepted that the injection of cheap money into developed economies is resulting in financial firms borrowing cheap at home to invest in emerging markets for profit, with little contribution to domestic recovery in the developed world. Emerging markets, on the other hand, are witnessing a capital inflow surge that is not merely triggering speculative booms in stock and real estate markets but also exerting upward pressure on their currencies. To expect them, therefore, to allow their currencies to appreciate further would be preposterous. In fact, despite resorting to capital controls to limit inflows as well as open market purchases of foreign currencies by the central bank to absorb surplus foreign exchange in domestic markets, countries such as Brazil have not been able to prevent appreciation of their currencies.

China, however, is a potential target for the currency baiters because of the trade and current account surpluses it runs and the reserves it has accumulated. This provides the basis for declaring that the country is manipulating its currency in mercantilist fashion to sustain growth at the expense of the rest of the world, especially the U.S. and Europe. Most recently, the U.S. House of Representatives passed, with a 348-to-79 majority, a Bill that allows the country to impose countervailing duties on imports from China. These duties are to be calibrated using estimates of the extent of undervaluation of the renminbi to signal that, in the U.S.' view, China is manipulating its currency for export gain and generating global current account imbalances in the process.

This round of China-bashing has been justified by referring to the evidence that while China unpegged the renminbi from the dollar in June this year, the currency has appreciated only marginally. Thus, the accusation is not that China is resorting to devaluation but that it has not permitted adequate appreciation despite its trade and current account surpluses, especially vis--vis the U.S.

What is surprising is that the House has resorted to this move despite evidence in the past, and even today, that intervention in various forms to prevent currency appreciation or even ensure depreciation of currencies has been the norm. The U.S., which protests much today, had exercised its global economic and political power to ensure the depreciation of the dollar vis--vis other leading currencies, especially the Japanese yen, through the Plaza Accord of 1985. A year and a half later, it engineered the Louvre Accord to prevent further decline of the dollar.

Currency manipulation is an old G8 practice. Most recently, the Bank of Japan intervened in its currency market to purchase $20 billion in return for Japanese yen, allowing it to stabilise an appreciating currency and ensure its depreciation from 83 yen to the dollar to around 85 yen to the dollar. Since the Japanese economy is still in deflationary mode, the injection of liquidity into the system to manage the currency does not stoke fears of inflation.

Japan's decision to intervene does weaken the legitimacy of the attack on the renminbi implicit in the U.S. Bill and of the pressure being mounted by the G20 on China to ensure further appreciation of the renminbi. However, while Japan's move has indeed been criticised by many of its trading partners, dissent is muted because of the recognition that Japan has suffered for long from a recession that was triggered in part by developments flowing from the appreciation of the yen consequent to the Plaza Accord.

Given its governance structure, it is not surprising that the IMF has joined this chorus. In its view, the sharp divergences in growth or uneven development in the global economy call for a process of external rebalancing, with an increase in net exports in deficit countries and a decrease in net exports in surplus countries, notably emerging Asia. This, in turn, is seen as requiring a realignment of currencies involving greater exchange rate flexibility, with an appreciation of the Chinese renminbi, for example, and a relative depreciation of the dollar and the euro.

Uneven development

There are a number of issues this argument glosses over. To start with, uneven development is an essential characteristic of capitalism, and in the past, for centuries, today's developed countries were the winners in a process that polarised the world into the developed and the underdeveloped. Underlying that polarisation was the consolidation of a division of labour wherein the developed were the producers of productivity-enhancing manufactured goods and the underdeveloped were left to live off the technologically less dynamic primary products that were losing out in world trade. What we have been observing in a gradual and limited manner over the past three decades is a partial reversal of this process, with a few emerging markets having turned winners in the trajectory involving uneven development.

Secondly, as the economist Prabhat Patnaik has argued, this shift in favour of emerging markets has been the outcome of the nature of recent processes of globalisation in which capital and technology have flowed easily across borders, while labour movement has been far less flexible and increasingly more limited. Since past processes of development have ensured that some of the more populous countries of the world (including China) were left with underutilised labour reserves, this differential in ease of cross-border movement led to the flow of capital in search of the cheap labour reserves in those parts of the developing world.

This has not only changed the pattern of uneven development, but since highly productive modern technology now combines with the cheap surplus labour in these countries, it results in a rise in the surpluses or profits garnered from production and therefore in inadequate consumption or under-consumption that depresses overall global output and employment growth. It must be noted that among the beneficiaries of this distorted process are also firms from the developed countries that seek to locate production facilities in these low-cost, labour surplus economies, and produce for world markets, including the markets of their countries of origin. Yet their role rarely receives the attention it deserves in discussions of global imbalance.

Finally, given these drivers of contemporary uneven development, adjusting any one currency, such as the renminbi, is unlikely to redress the global imbalances. It would at most merely shift the balance of payments surpluses to other countries with labour reserves that would now become the new hubs for world market production.

Despite all this, since countries that are the target of capital inflows are finding it difficult to prevent the appreciation of their currencies, the U.S. and Europe are receiving explicit or implicit support for the China-bashing. Central banks from many other countries have been and are intervening in currency markets to hold down the value of their currencies but have not been very successful. This is true, for example, of South Korea, India, Malaysia, Taiwan, the Philippines and Singapore. Their moves have received global attention ever since Guido Mantega, Brazil's Finance Minister, declared that a currency war had broken out in the global economy. We're in the midst of an international currency war, a general weakening of currency. This threatens us because it takes away our competitiveness, Mantega reportedly said. In doing so he was being disingenuous because Brazil's immediate problem is not the weakening of the currencies of its competitors but the appreciation of the Brazilian real, which has been identified as one of the world's most overvalued currencies.

In fact, overvaluation that affects export competitiveness adversely seems to be the factor accounting for currency market interventions by central banks in most countries. The explanation for such overvaluation is the surge in foreign capital flow to these countries in the period between 2003 and the Great Recession and once again over the past one year. Intervention to address the excessive strength of individual currencies is costly since the reserves accumulated by buying foreign currency have to be invested in liquid financial assets that offer very low yields, while the foreign investors bringing in the dollars that lead to appreciation of the local currency earn substantially high returns. Moreover, for countries that do not have the advantage of low inflation and low interest rates, the problem can be never-ending. Thus, in India, for example, increases in interest rates aimed at combating inflation are resulting in further inflows and a substantial strengthening of the rupee.

The implications are clear. The resort to monetary easing in the developed counties, with another round of such easing expected in the U.S. after figures pointing to the loss of 95,000 jobs in September were released, is triggering a boom in the carry-trade. Financial investors borrow cheap in dollars and put their money in emerging markets to earn high returns.

In the event, emerging market countries unwilling to impose controls on capital inflows experience a capital surge and invite an appreciation of their currencies. Since such appreciation undermines their export competitiveness, they are forced to intervene in currency markets to limit or reverse such appreciation. To justify this costly way of dealing with the problem created by fluid capital flows, they point their fingers at other countries that are preventing currency appreciation. China comes in useful here, not just because it severely limits appreciation but because it is a successful exporter and records current account surpluses.

Thus, joining the American clamour against China becomes a way of deflecting attention from the fact that the failure to export enough stems from an inadequacy of domestic policies rather than the aggressive currency moves of others. This currency war blame game makes the prospect of progress on formulating a coordinated recovery plan at the G20 summit in Seoul in November very dim.

Sign in to Unlock member-only benefits!
  • Bookmark stories to read later.
  • Comment on stories to start conversations.
  • Subscribe to our newsletters.
  • Get notified about discounts and offers to our products.
Sign in

Comments

Comments have to be in English, and in full sentences. They cannot be abusive or personal. Please abide to our community guidelines for posting your comment