That shrinking feeling

The value of global financial assets grew rapidly in the decade up to 2007, but has fallen sharply since then. A new report suggests that the global financial crisis caused the financial froth to subside.

Published : Mar 21, 2013 14:05 IST

IT is obvious that the recent boom in global capitalism has witnessed massive over-extension of finance. What has been described as “financialisation” reflected the ever-greater penetration of finance capital into more and more activities of the real economy and its involvement in critical markets such as those for commodity futures, that affect traded prices of food and fuel. It also reflected the also huge and volatile movements of capital across national borders. By 2007, global stocks of financial assets (both equity and debt stocks) amounted to $206 trillion. This meant that financial assets were more than four times the maximal estimate of gross domestic product (GDP) in developed countries in that year, and nearly twice the value of GDP in developing countries.

But did this actually change from 2008? Is it the case that the global financial crisis and its ramifications have actually had some effect in causing this financial froth to subside? A new report from the McKinsey Global Institute based on its database of financial assets in 183 countries suggests that this might be the case.

( Financial Globalisation: Retreat or reset? , March 2013, McKinsey Global Institute, http://www.mckinsey.com/insights/mgi/research/financial_markets/financial_globalization)

Rapid growth, sharp fall According to this report, the estimated value of global financial assets grew rapidly (by more than 8 per cent per annum) in the decade up to 2007, but since then they have grown by less than 2 per cent per annum. Cross-border capital flows fell sharply to $2.2 trillion in 2008, from $11.8 trillion in 2007 (at constant 2011 exchange rates). In 2012, they were estimated at $4.6 trillion, around 40 per cent lower than the 2007 peak. Equity assets and securitised loans have actually declined in value.

Much of this was on account of reduction of capital flows within the developed world. The European economic crisis played an important role in this—nearly half of the decline in cross-border capital flows was because of Western Europe alone. For example, since the last quarter of 2007 eurozone banks have reduced foreign claims by $3.7 trillion. Of this amount, $2.8 trillion was on other banks within Europe, with $1.2 trillion only on banks from the crisis-ridden GIPSI (Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spain and Italy) countries. But even in developing countries, the process of financial expansion is slowing down, though it still continues, especially with the continuing growth in bond markets.

This is essentially good news. Most of the increase in finance in the “roaring 2000s”, up to 2007, was not just unsustainable—it was unnecessary and even undesirable. It did generate booms in some advanced countries (particularly the United States and some European countries), which in turn fuelled export-driven expansion in some developing countries including China. But this was only because finance provided a means of compensating for the potential stagnation and lack of demand owing to the growing inequalities in income distribution. By generating demand through borrowing rather than actual incomes, finance also accentuated asset inequalities, putting more money in the hands of financial intermediaries while drawing people, companies and even governments into eventually unrepayable debts.

The pyramiding of finance meant the creation of an essentially top-heavy and extremely entangled system, not just within countries but globally. Most of the so-called “financial deepening” of that period was due to financial system leverage (as banks and other players essentially borrowed from one another) increasing stock market valuations. “Plain vanilla” credit stopped being the purpose of the financial system, and instead became the base for an ever more complex system of securitisation and other extensions.

Illusion Financial “innovation” in the form of new instruments and products as well as forays into markets such as those of commodity futures created a sense of dynamism that was an illusion and not based on any real contribution to the economy. Instead, the boom was associated with all sorts of speculative capital movements that were oriented to risky high-return assets and created a very uneven and imbalanced expansion. The inadequate monitoring, in turn, was associated not just with irresponsible behaviour but downright malpractice, all masked by the prevailing financial euphoria.

As we have found repeatedly to our cost but still do not seem to learn, such bubbles must burst. The year 2008 marked one such puncturing, but not a complete one. Indeed, the relatively slow reduction in financial valuations and the renewed profitability of banks and other financial institutions (with the continuing award of bonuses for senior managers) suggest that, if anything, the process has still not gone far enough. Clearly, more reductions in finance are required and will eventually occur.

The concerns about global finance may be even greater for developing countries. While it is true that these countries still show significantly lower ratios of “financial deepening” it is evident that this is not necessarily a bad thing. But these countries continue to exhibit some of the more glaring anomalies of the implications of the global organisation of finance, such as the continuing net flows of capital from the South to the North.

Global capital inflows to developing countries halved from $1.6 trillion in 2007 to only $0.8 trillion in 2009. They have since recovered to $1.5 trillion in 2012. But—and here is the rub —capital outflows from developing countries also increased and also continued to be more than inflows. In 2012 such outflows amounted to $1.8 trillion. Just under half of this was in the form of reserve holding by central banks, but foreign direct investment (FDI), cross-border loans and portfolio investment account for increasing shares.

Most of the developing countries’ foreign assets are in advanced countries, showing how perceptions of power continue to dominate financial decisions even in the developing world. There is much talk of increased South-South investment, and this has certainly increased. But it is still minor compared with the extent to which the developing world continues to finance the rich North, especially the U.S.

Thus, while $12.4 trillion of foreign investment assets of the developing world are held in the North, South-South stocks of such investment are only $1.9 trillion—amounting to just 2 per cent of all cross-border foreign investment assets. So the developing world as a whole—and each one of the major constituent regions—continues to be a net funder of the developed economies.

China factor The largest impact of outward investment from developing countries is, of course, that of China. Certainly in absolute terms and in rate of growth, China’s global financial presence has been significant. China is now a much larger funder than the World Bank in both Africa and Latin America, and its FDI has also been impressive in the last decade. Even so, China’s investment abroad is dominated by the North. Thus, around half of the total non-foreign exchange reserve holding of foreign assets by the Chinese government and Chinese companies (around $1.5 trillion) is to other developing countries—but, the rest is in advanced countries.

Meanwhile, most of the foreign holdings are in the form of central bank reserves, which are currently estimated at more than $3.2 trillion. So foreign assets held in other developing countries still come to only around 15 per cent of China’s total foreign assets. So even China, whose impact in the developing world is so significant, still directs the greater bulk of its outward investment to advanced economies.

Bubbles in the making Meanwhile, the other concern is that many developing countries are trying to cope with the continuing ramifications of the global crisis by generating their own bubbles in domestic asset markets. This happens in a variety of ways: stimulus measures that target sectors such as real estate and housing; other fiscal concessions granted to encourage more financial saving and investment; liberal rules for extension of consumer finance for purchase of durable goods; financial liberalisation measures that encourage more expansion of the sector; and so on.

These may create mini-booms in certain economies, but these are temporary at best and in the current fragile external environment they may be even more short-lived. And the bursting of those bubbles will be even more painful in the context of the global economic headwinds. At the same time, they will also encourage the same tendencies that continue to make developing countries export capital to the North, at the cost of meeting their own citizens’ needs and fulfilling their own development projects.

So it is more important than ever to restrain finance, since that task is clearly incomplete. To make the financial system fulfil the basic tasks for which it is supposed to exist—to direct savings to productive investment in a stable and socially desirable way—it is essential to shrink it further.

You have exhausted your free article limit.
Get a free trial and read Frontline FREE for 15 days
Signup and read this article for FREE

More stories from this issue

Get unlimited access to premium articles, issues, and all-time archives